Добавил:
Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
Mark International Macroeconomics and Finance Theory and Empirical Methods.pdf
Скачиваний:
86
Добавлен:
22.08.2013
Размер:
2.29 Mб
Скачать

Chapter 11

Balance of Payments Crises

In chapter 10 we argued that there is a presumption that any Þxed exchange rate regime must eventually collapse–a presumption that the data supports. Britain and the U.S. were forced o of the gold standard during WWI and the Great Depression. More recent collapses occurred in the face of crushing speculative attacks on central bank reserves. Some well-known foreign exchange crises include the breakdown of the 1946—1971 IMF system of Þxed but adjustable exchange rates, Mexico and Argentina during the 1970s and early 1980s, the European Monetary System in 1992, Mexico in 1994, and the Asian Crisis of 1997. Evidently, no Þxed exchange rate regime has ever truly been Þxed.

This chapter covers models of the causes and the timing of currency crises. We begin with what Flood and Marion [57] call Þrst generation models. This class of models, developed to explain balance of payments crises experienced by developing countries during the 1970s and 1980s. These crises were often preceded by unsustainably large government Þscal deÞcits, Þnanced by excessive domestic credit creation that eventually exhausted the central bank’s foreign exchange reserves. Consequently, Þrst-generation models emphasize macroeconomic mismanagement as the primary cause of the crisis. They suggest that the size of a country’s Þnancial liabilities (the government’s Þscal deÞcit, short term debt and the current account deÞcit) relative to its short run ability to pay (foreign exchange reserves) and/or a sustained real appreciation from domestic price level inßation should signal an increasing likelihood of a crisis.

327

328

CHAPTER 11. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS CRISES

In more recent experience such as the European Monetary System crisis of 1992 or the Asian crisis of 1997, few of the a ected countries appeared to be victims of macroeconomic mismanagement. These crises seemed to occur independently of the macroeconomic fundamentals and do not Þt into the mold of the Þrst generation models. Secondgeneration models were developed to understand these phenomenon. In these models, the government explicitly balances the costs of defending the exchange rate against the beneÞts of realignment. The government’s decision rule gives rise to multiple equilibria in which the costs of exchange rate defense depend on the public’s expectations. A shift in the public’s expectations can alter the government’s cost-beneÞt calculation resulting in a shift from an equilibrium with a low-probability of devaluation to one with a high-probability of devaluation. Because an ensuing crisis is made more likely by changing public opinion, these models are also referred to as models of self-fulÞlling crises.

11.1A First-Generation Model

In Þrst-generation models, the government exogeneously pursues Þscal and monetary policies that are inconsistent with the long-run maintenance of a Þxed exchange rate. One way to motivate government behavior of this sort is to argue that the government faces short-term domestic Þnancing constraints that it feels are more important to satisfy than long-run maintenance of external balance. While this is not a completely satisfactory way to model the actions of the authorities, it allows us to focus on the behavior of speculators and their role in generating a crisis.

Speculators observe the decline of the central bank’s international reserves and time a speculative attack in which they acquire the remaining reserves in an instant. Faced with the loss of all of its foreign exchange reserves, the central bank is forced to abandon the peg and to move to a free ßoat. The speculative attack on the central bank at during the Þnal moments of the peg is called a balance of payments or a foreign exchange crisis. The original contribution is due to Krugman [89]. We’ll study the linear version of that model developed by Flood and Garber [55].

11.1. A FIRST-GENERATION MODEL

329

Flood—Garber Deterministic Crises

The model is based on the deterministic, continuous-time monetary model of a small open economy of Chapter 10.2. All variables except for the interest rate are expressed as logarithms–m(t) is the domestic money supply, p(t) the price level, i(t) the nominal interest rate, d(t) domestic credit, and r(t) the home-currency value of foreign exchange reserves. From the log-linearization of the central bank’s balance sheet identity, the log money supply can be decomposed as

m(t) = γd(t) + (1 − γ)r(t).

(11.1)

Domestic income is assumed to be Þxed. We normalize units such that y(t) = y = 0. The money market equilibrium condition is

m(t) − p(t) = −αi(t).

(11.2)

The model is completed by invoking purchasing-power parity and uncovered interest parity

s(t)

= p(t),

(11.3)

i(t)

= Et[sú(t)] = sú(t),

(11.4)

where we have set the exogenous log foreign price level and the exoge-

nous foreign interest rate both to zero p = i = 0.

Combine (11.2)—

(11.4) to obtain the di erential equation,

(219)

m(t) − s(t) = −αsú(t)

(11.5)

The authorities establish a Þxed exchange rate regime at t = 0 by pegging the exchange rate at its t = 0 equilibrium value, s¯ = m(0). During the time that the Þx is in e ect, sú(t) = 0. By (11.5), the authorities must maintain a Þxed money supply at m(t) = s¯ to defend the exchange rate.

Suppose that the domestic credit component grows at the rate dú(t) = µ. The government may do this because it lacks an adequate tax base and money creation is the only way to pay for government spending. But keeping the money supply Þxed in the face of expanding domestic credit means reserves must decline at the rate

rú(t) =

−γ

dú(t) =

−µγ

.

(11.6)

1 − γ

1 − γ

330

CHAPTER 11. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS CRISES

Clearly this policy is inconsistent with the long-run maintenance of the Þxed exchange rate since the government will eventually run out of foreign exchange reserves.

Non-attack exhaustion of reserves. If reserves are permitted to decline at the rate in (11.6) without interruption, it is straightforward to determine the time tN at which they will be exhausted. Reserves at any time 0 < t < tN are the initial level of reserves minus reserves lost between 0 and t

r(t) =

r(0)

+ Z0t

rú(u)du

=

r(0)

Z0t(γµ/(1 − γ))du

=

r(0)

− γµ/(1 − γ)t.

Since reserves are exhausted at tN , set r(tN ) = 0 = r(0)−γµ/(1−γ)tN . Solving for tN gives

tN =

r(0)(1 − γ)

.

(11.7)

 

γµ

 

Time of attack. The time-path for reserves described above is not your typical balance of payments crises. Central banks usually do not have the luxury of watching their reserves smoothly decline to zero. Instead, Þxed exchange rates usually end with a balance-of-payments crisis in which speculators mount an attack and instantaneously acquire the remaining reserves of the central bank.

Economic agents know that the exchange rate must ßoat at tN . They anticipate that the exchange rate will make a discrete jump at the time of abandonment. To avoid realizing losses on domestic currency assets, agents attempt to convert the soon-to-be over-valued domestic currency into foreign currency at tA < tN . This sudden rush into long positions in the foreign currency will cause an immediate exhaustion of available reserves. Call tA the time of attack.

To solve for tA, let s˜(t) be the shadow-value of the exchange rate. It is the hypothetical value of the exchange rate given that the central bank has run out of reserves.1 Market participants will attack if s¯ <

1The home currency is ‘overvalued’ if s¯ < s˜(t). A proÞtable speculative strategy

11.1. A FIRST-GENERATION MODEL

331

Money

Money

d(0)

Domestic credit

r(0)

 

 

Reserves

0

tA

time

tN

Figure 11.1: Time-path of monetary aggregates under the Þx and its collapse.

s˜(t). They will not attack if s¯ > s˜. But if s¯ < s˜(t), the attack will result in a discrete jump in the exchange rate of s˜(t) − s¯. The jump presents an opportunity to proÞts of unlimited size which is a violation of uncovered interest parity. We rule out such proÞts in equilibrium.

Thus, the time of attack can be determined by Þnding t = tA such that s˜(tA) = s¯. First obtain for s˜(t) by the method of undetermined coe cients. Since the ‘fundamentals’ are comprised only of m(t) conjecture the solution s˜(t) = a0 + a1m(t). Taking time-derivatives of the guess solution yields sú(t) = a1mú (t) = a1γµ, where the second equality follows from mú (t) = γdú(t) = γµ. Substitute the guess solution into the basic di erential equation (11.5), and equate coe cients on the constant and m(t), to get a0 = αγµ and a1 = 1. You now have

s˜(t) = αγµ + m(t).

(11.8)

would be to borrow the home currency at an interest rate i(t), use the borrowed funds to buy the foreign currency from the central bank at s¯. After the Þx collapses, sell the foreign currency at s˜(t), repay the loans, and pocket a nice proÞt.

332

CHAPTER 11. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS CRISES

When reserves are exhausted, r(t) = 0, and the money supply becomes

m(t) = γd(t) = γ

[d(0) + Z0t dú(u)du] = γ[d(0) + µt].

 

Substitute m(t) into (11.8)

to get

 

s˜(t) = γ[d(0) + µt] + αγµ.

(11.9)

Setting s˜(tA) = s¯ = m(0) = γd(0) + (1 − γ)r(0) and solving for the time of attack gives

tA = (1 − γ)r(0) − α = tN − α.

γµ

The level of reserves at the point of attack is

r(tA) = r(0) −

µγ

µαγ

 

 

tA =

 

> 0.

1 − γ

1 − γ

(11.10)

(11.11)

Figure 11.1 illustrates the time-path of money and its components when there is an attack. One of the key features of the model is that episodes of large asset market volatility, namely the attack, does not coincide with big news or corresponding large events. The attack comes suddenly but is the rational response of speculators to the accumulated e ects of domestic credit creation that is inconsistent with the Þxed exchange rate in the long run.

One dissatisfying feature of the deterministic model is that the attack is perfectly predictable. Another feature is that there is no transfer of wealth. In actual crises, the attacks are largely unpredictable and typically result in sizable transfers of wealth from the central bank (with costs ultimately borne by taxpayers) to speculators.

A stochastic Þrst-generation model.

Let’s now extend the Flood and Garber model to a stochastic environment. We will not be able to solve for the date of attack but we can model the conditional probability of an attack. In discrete time,

11.1. A FIRST-GENERATION MODEL

 

333

let the economic environment be given by

 

 

mt

=

γdt + (1 − γ)rt,

(11.12)

mt − pt

=

−αit,

 

(11.13)

pt

=

st,

 

(11.14)

it = Et(∆st+1).

(11.15)

Let domestic credit be governed by the random walk

 

dt = (µ −

1

) + dt−1

+ vt,

(11.16)

 

λ

where vt is drawn from the exponential distribution.2. Also, assume that the domestic credit process has an upward drift µ > 1/λ. At time t, agents attack the central bank if s˜t ≥ s¯, where s˜ is the shadow exchange rate.

Let the publicly available information set be It and let pt be the probability of an attack at t + 1 conditional on It. Then,

pt =

Pr[˜st+1 > s¯|It]

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

= Pr[αγµ + mt+1 − s¯ > 0|It]

 

 

 

 

=

Pr[αγµ + γdt+1 − s¯ > 0|It]

+ vt+1− s¯ > 0|It¸

 

= Pr ·αγµ + γ µdt + ·µ − λ¸

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

1

 

 

 

 

 

= Pr "vt+1

> γ s¯ − (1 + α)µ − dt + λ|It#

 

 

 

 

1

 

 

 

 

1

 

 

=

Pr(vt+1

> θt|It)

1

θt

< 0

 

 

 

 

Z

θt

(

 

 

 

=

λe−λudu =

e−λθt

θt

≥ 0

(11.17)

 

where θt ≡ (1/γ)¯s − (1 − α)µ − dt + (1/λ). The rational exchange rate forecast error is

Etst+1 − s¯ = pt[Et(˜st+1) − s¯],

(11.18)

and is systematic if pt > 0.

2A random variable X has the exponential distribution if for x ≥ 0, f(x) = λe−λx. The mean of the distribution is E(X) = 1/λ.

334

CHAPTER 11. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS CRISES

Thus there will be a peso problem as long as the Þx is in e ect. By (11.17), we know how pt behaves. Now let’s characterize Et(˜st+1) and the forecast errors. First note that

Et(˜st+1) = αγµ + γEt(dt+1)

 

=

αγµEt ·µ − λ + dt + vt+1¸

 

 

1

 

 

 

1

 

 

 

=

αγµ + µ −

 

+ dt + Et(vt+1).

(11.19)

λ

Et(vt+1) is computed conditional on a collapse next period which will occur if vt+1 > θt. To Þnd the probability density function of v conditional on a collapse, normalize the density of v such that the probability that vt+1 > θt is 1 by solving for the normalizing constant φ in

(222) 1 = φ Rθt λe−λudu. This yields φ = eλθt . It follows that the probability density conditional on a collapse next period is

|

 

(

λe−λu

θt

< 0

f(u

collapse) =

λeλ(θt−u)

u ≥ θt ≥ 0

and

 

 

 

 

 

( R0uλe−λudu = λ1

 

θt < 0

Et(vt+1) =

R

θt uλeλ(θt−u)du = θt + λ1

θt ≥ 0

 

 

 

 

 

,

.(11.20)

Now substitute (11.20) into (11.19) and simplify to obtain

(

(1 + α)γµ + γdt

θt < 0

 

Et(˜st+1) =

s¯ + λγ

θt ≥ 0 .

(11.21)

Substituting (11.21) into (11.18) you get the systematic but rational forecast errors predicted by the model

( (1 + α)γµ + γdt

 

s¯ θt < 0

 

 

ptγ

 

θt ≥ 0 .

 

Et(st+1) s¯ =

λ

(11.22)