Добавил:
Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:

The Economic History of Byzantium From

.pdf
Скачиваний:
2
Добавлен:
16.04.2024
Размер:
19.01 Mб
Скачать

Byzantine Money: Its Production and Circulation

965

conditions under which ambassadors procured, in Venice (?) or in Constantinople, the Byzantine coins they needed to cover their expenses in the capital. Abundant though they are, documents in southern Italy tell us nothing about the rate of exchange between the tari and the nomisma, though a Venetian document of 1000 or 1001 indicates that 4 bisantii aurei were worth 2 pounds of denarii, or 1 nomisma 120 denarii,161 whereas in Hungary, the nomisma ( pensa auri), initially valued in trade at 30 denarii (of the Bavarian type, the prototype for the Hungarian coinage), was subsequently fixed at 40 deniers by Bela I (1061–63).162 In the twelfth century, the various accounts of the crusades and a few Venetian documents give values for the hyperpyron expressed in a variety of denarii (in 1196 480 Venetian denarii) or in silver marks, corresponding to a weight between 28 g and 60 g of fine silver. According to Odo of Deuil, French Crusaders changed a staminum for 5 denarii (parisis?) in the Balkans, for 5 or 6 in Asia Minor, and for only 2 at Constantinople, thanks to the agreement that had been concluded with Manuel I. At 0.39 g of fine silver each, these 2 denarii that were exchanged for a piece with a theoretical value of 148 of a hyperpyron (3.65 g fine gold) imply a gold:silver ratio of 1:10.3, which is not far from the 1:11.9 ratio that has been deduced from the explicit accord drawn up between Frederick I and Isaac II, fixing the price of the mark (231.16 g silver) at 512 hyperpyra (19.4 g gold), i.e., 1 hyperpyron to 42 g silver.163

The Venetian documents assembled by Bertele` allow us to follow the decline of the hyperpyron in terms of the hard currencies that replaced it as international media of exchange in the thirteenth century.164 The currency market was henceforth open: the treaty of Nymphaion (1261) authorized the export of hyperpyra, and we know they also reached Venice where they were melted down. The export of silver and gold from Venice to the Levant was certainly far more important than currency movements between Venice and Constantinople. However, the galleys that transported silver to Constantinople and the Black Sea brought back gold, and Byzantine gold, along with gold from the Sudan, Germany, and Transylvania, continued to support the abundant minting of ducats that took off at the beginning of the fourteenth century. The rate of exchange for hyperpyra and ducats (see Table 7) was determined primarily by their respective precious metal content. However, the rate of 2 hyperpyra to a ducat in the middle of the fourteenth century overestimates the Venetian coinage by some 10% and

161B. Callegher, “Presenza di ‘folles anonimi’ in Italia settentrionale: Un’ipotesi interpretativa,”

Numismatica e antichita` classiche. Quaderni Ticinesi 23 (1994): 293–312.

162B. Homan, “La circolazione delle monete d’oro in Ungheria dal X al XIV secolo e la crisi europea dell’oro nel secolo XIV,” RIN (1922): 111.

163Hendy, “Coinage,” 14, 21; A. E. Laiou, “Byzantine Trade with Christians and Muslims and the Crusades,” in The Crusades from the Perspective of Byzantium and the Muslim World, ed. A. E. Laiou and R. Mottahedeh (Washington, D.C., 2001), 158–96. Bertele`, Moneta veneziana, 31–34. Fluctuations in the value of the hyperpyron, given that its precious metal content was stable, were due to the greater or lesser rigidity of the market and above all to variations in the gold:silver ratio.

164Bertele`, Moneta veneziana, appendix 3, 39–58 (figures in Venetian grossi have been converted to hyperpyra according to the number of grossi to the ducat in the relevant period).

´

966 CECILE MORRISSON

Table 7

The Hyperpyron in Venetian Gold Ducats

Date

1315

1 hyperpyron 23

ducat

1 ducat 1.5 hyperpyra

1323

1 hyperpyron 0.58 ducat

1 ducat 1.75 hyperpyra

1333

1 hyperpyron 0.48 ducat

1 ducat 2.08 hyperpyra

1367

1 hyperpyron 12

ducat

1 ducat 2 hyperpyra

 

 

(accounts for the expedition of Amadeus IV of Savoy)

1382–91

1 hyperpyron 25

ducat

1 ducat 2.5 hyperpyra

1397–1411

1 hyperpyron 310 ducat

1 ducat 313 hyperpyra

 

 

 

(official exchange rate for galleys)

1413–20

1 hyperpyron 0.26 ducat

1 ducat 3 hyperpyra 18 carats

1432–52

1 hyperpyron 0.28–0.34 ducat

1 ducat 3 hyperpyra 12 carats

 

 

 

to 22 hyperpyra 22 carats

 

 

 

(Badoer and Barbarigo’s accounts)

 

 

 

 

is evidence of the suspicion with which the “discredited” Byzantine coinage was viewed. Its fall cannot be attributed solely to the crisis of public finances.165

The declining value of the silver hyperpyron, compared with the ducat, dates from the turn of the fourteenth century. It antedated the reduction in fineness observed under John VIII (1425–48); in the same way, the reestablishment of the exchange rate with an average value of 3 hyperpyra to the ducat preceded the return under Constantine XI (1448–53) to the purity of the first issues in the fourteenth century. As might be expected in theory, this discrepancy shows that the essential element in fixing this rate was the evolution of the gold:silver ratio, itself influenced by mine production, which we know to have been particularly abundant in Serbia and Bosnia between 1400 and 1420, after which output again diminished.166 The relative stability of the preciousmetal coinage at the end of the empire affords a glimpse of the way the coinage was controlled privately and was thus removed from the imperial finances and their notorious indigence, quite the opposite situation to the one that undoubtedly prevailed from the beginning of the empire until the reign of the first Palaiologoi.

165F. C. Lane, “Exportations ve´nitiennes d’or et d’argent de 1200 `a 1450,” in Etudes d’histoire mone´- taire, ed. J. Day (Lille, 1984), 32–33; Hendy, Studies, 546–47; Morrisson, “Monnaie et finances dans l’Empire byzantin,” 312–13.

166Spufford, Money, 349–51.

A Note on Monetary Mechanisms, East and West

John Day

By the age of Justinian the monetary institutions of the Byzantine Empire already differed substantially from those of Latin Europe. In Byzantium the coinage continued to serve as an instrument of power in a centralized state at a time when it was increasingly fragmented—and increasingly rare—in the barbarian West (feudalism was born in the 7th century, writes Peter Spufford, when the Frankish kings ran out of gold to pay their armies).1 If the Carolingian reforms marked the return to a uniform coinage system in the western empire—but based on a silver denarius rather than a gold sol- idus—the process of monetary disintegration resumed under Charlemagne’s successors with the concession of minting privileges to great vassals or subject towns who altered the characteristics of the coins at their pleasure.

It was the disappearance of gold coinage in most of Europe and the general retreat from a market economy that consecrated the divorce between monetary practices East and West. But the economic expansion of the twelfth to thirteenth centuries, marked by the activities of western traders and Crusaders in the Levant, initiated a movement of convergence. The conjunction remained incomplete, however, because the western economies were soon embarked on the adventure of merchant capitalism based on monetary institutions and capital resources that were without their equivalent in Islam and Byzantium.2

In medieval Europe, long-term economic movements and long-term monetary movements were inseparable because the former were dependent in large measure on the supply of money (and not the other way around, as in the case of modern economies), that is, on the production and distribution of the monetary metals. Moreover, in that age of metallic circulation, the supply was never equal to the demand, resulting in constant complaints that money was “scarce” (in some periods, obviously, more than

1P. Spufford, Money and Its Use in Medieval Europe (Cambridge, 1988), 16.

2It should be noted that Byzantium was perhaps less backward in this respect than the dearth of documentation suggests, as witness its integration into the Italian world of maritime trade (albeit as a “junior partner”) in the late Middle Ages. A. E. Laiou, “The Byzantine Economy in the Mediterranean Trade System, Thirteenth–Fifteenth Centuries,” in Laiou, Gender, Society and Economic Life in Byzantium (Hampshire, 1992), 172–79.

968 JOHN DAY

in others) and in what Marc Bloch termed “the obscure need to inflate the currency.”3 In practice, except in the case of the deliberate manipulation of the coinage as a revenue measure, the minting authorities “inflated the currency” to offset a rise in the price of the monetary metals which posed a threat, by virtue of Gresham’s Law, to the current circulation.

In Byzantium, as late as the twelfth century, the permanent stock of monetary metals seems on the whole to have remained remarkably stable. Irretrievable losses were replenished from new mine production, tribute from foreign rulers, or favorable trade balances, so that there existed in practice the sort of equilibrium evoked by those economists who postulate the neutrality of money and the necessary adjustment of the money supply to the state of trade. The “equilibrium,” not surprisingly, extended to the prices of most commodities, some of which owed their relative stability, however, to government controls, particularly in times of crisis.

In the medieval European economies, on the contrary, not only were monetary stocks chronically insufficient, but their distribution often responded to the noneconomic imperatives of “guerres mone´taires” (competitive debasements) in a neverending “struggle for bullion.” The movement of prices, for its part, tended to mirror fluctuations in the money supply, and price and wage controls, for example in the wake of the Black Death, proved impossible to enforce.4

Because of the constant flux and reflux of monetary stocks according to harvest cycles, shipping movements, trade fairs, the tax calendar, and the international balance of payments, it is difficult to follow the process of monetization of the medieval economy which, in any case, was far from uniform or irreversible. In Europe, despite the development of credit and even, in some instances, of substitutes for metallic currency such as bank money, deposit certificates, or financial clearings, barter continued to play an important role in economic relations precisely because the circulation was limited and inelastic. But by the time of the Crusades it was no longer practiced on a grand scale, except in trade with the Levant where parallel price lists confirm that cash prices were invariably lower than barter prices,5 a fact that went hand in hand with a regular premium on silver bullion or coin. Barter, in short, continued to flourish in the Levant trade because of the persistent shortage of cash and the backward state of credit.

It should be noted that in this instance a low degree of “monetization” (the proportion of transactions conducted with the actual physical exchange of coins or surrogate currencies), which necessitates recourse to the exchange of goods for goods, does not signify a primitive system of exchange (any more than swap agreements between nations do today), let alone a “natural economy.”

3M. Bloch, Esquisse d’une histoire mone´taire de l’Europe (Paris, 1954), 63–65. Cf. J. Day, “L’histoire de la monnaie dans les ´ecrits de Marc Bloch,” in Monnaies et marche´s au Moyen Age (Paris, 1994), 271–81.

4Cf. J. Day, “Crises et conjonctures `a la fin du Moyen Age,” in Monnaies et marche´s au Moyen Age (as above, note 3), 213–49.

5E. Ashtor, “Pagamento in contanti e baratto nel commercio italiano d’oltremare, secoli XIV–XVI,” in Economia naturale, economia monetaria, ed. R. Romano and U. Tucci, Storia d’Italia, Annali 6 (Turin, 1983), 363–96.

Monetary Mechanisms, East and West

969

The choice of the type of coinage (one is reminded of Marc Bloch’s characterization of gold coins as a “monnaie de classe”) depended in the first instance on the kind and quantities of monetary metals available for minting. Because of an acute shortage of silver, Portugal, in the first half of the sixteenth century, then one of the great European powers, relied on a domestic circulation of pure copper coins (silver and gold coins were reserved for international accounts).6 But the choice could also be determined simply by custom. At Genoa in the seventeenth century, to cite a postmedieval example, it was the practice to pay for Lombard grain and bills of exchange in gold scudi, while silk from Calabria and Genoese customs duties were paid in silver scudi, and French and English grain merchants insisted on Spanish reales.7 In the absence of statements of payment or similar documents with breakdowns by type of coin, one is left in the dark about monetary usages in Byzantium, except as revealed through the analysis of coin hoards, but they were probably at least as unpredictable as in the West.

The “problem of the standard” (to use the expression of another age) that afflicted the European economies in the late Middle Ages was the result of fluctuations in the prices of gold and silver or the deterioration of the coins in terms of which prices were expressed (the “link money” or money of account).8 The creation of new standards, or accounting systems, in an effort to stabilize the currency, occurred as a rule on the occasion of the creation of a new coin type; for example, the Venetian silver grosso of ca. 1200 at 24d. (2 shillings), the Florentine gold florin of 1252 at 20 silver florins of 12 billon piccoli each, the French ´ecu of 1266 equal to 10 gros tournois or 120 deniers tournois. In all of these cases the authorities attempted unsuccessfully to incorporate coins made of different metal in a single standard.

The Venetian grosso at 24d. rose almost immediately to 26d., then to 32d. because of the deterioration of the piccolo giving rise to a parallel standard based on the prestigious grosso, which remained perfectly stable for the next 150 years. Similarly, the florin and the ´ecu rapidly detached themselves from the silver-based currency because of the rise of gold and the inevitable deterioration of the billon money. On account of the impossibility of enforcing a legal bimetallic ratio (in practice, the price of gold coins in terms of silver coins), parallel gold and silver or gold and silver-billon standards were in fact common, especially in the period 1250–1350 (after the return to gold coinage in the West) when the market ratio was changing rapidly, first in favor of gold, then in favor of silver.

In the course of time, bimetallic systems were abandoned or transformed into monometallic systems, normally while retaining their former designation. The Venetian “ducat” of 124 soldi. from the early sixteenth century on was actually a silver-based money of account. The Genoese and Milanese “florins” of 25 soldi and 32 soldi respec-

6J. Day, “The Problem of the Standard in Preindustrial Europe,” in Money and Finance in the Age of Merchant Capitalism (Oxford, 1999), 59–109.

7G. Gianelli, “Problemi monetari genovesi del Seicento: La questione della ‘moneta specifica,’” in

Scritti in onore del professore Paolo Emilio Taviani (Genoa, 1983–86), 1:177–94.

8For what follows, see J. Day, “Les monnaies de compte me´die´vales et le proble`me de l’e´talon,” in

Monnaies et marche´s au Moyen Age (as above, note 3), 251–70.

970 JOHN DAY

tively became simple notional multiples of the devalued billon currency after about 1400. The various systems of account based on the gros tournois and a current gold piece in France in the fourteenth century all ended up as gold standards alongside the silver-billon standard (the livre tournois).

The old debate concerning the nature and function of the money of account, sometimes referred to as “ghost money,” was confined, not by accident, to continental scholars (Marc Bloch, Hans van Werveke, Henri Laurent, the economist Luigi Einaudi). England in fact remained faithful to the sterling standard, which first suffered serious reductions in weight in the course of the late medieval “bullion famine” but never a reduction in fineness. Debased billon money, elsewhere the basis of the system of account, was unknown. The basic denomination, the penny—as well as the halfpenny and farthing—was of good silver. And gold money was quoted in sterling. Hence it was not necessary to invent a “money of account” to accommodate a heterogeneous and unstable circulation as in continental Europe.

The second major cause of monetary instability—the deterioration of the silverbillon circulation through wear and tear, clipping, culling, and counterfeiting—made it impossible to continue coinage at the current mint standard since newly minted pieces would immediately have fallen victim to Gresham’s Law. To escape the consequences of monetary deflation, induced by the recall and recoinage of the entire circulation, one solution was to abandon the minting of the basic coinage altogether. This is what occurred, for example, in the fourteenth to fifteenth centuries in Catalonia, where the king was forbidden by statute to “mutate” the ancient diner de tern. The public came to accept worn Aragonese diners or Valencian menuts at their nominal value in small transactions but insisted on gold florins or silver croats in large transactions. A similar situation existed in seventeenth-century England, where the sterling money deteriorated by half in silver content leading to the famous polemic that pitted John Locke and the stable money school against the “devaluationists”.9 In both cases the result was a semi-fiduciary circulation imposed by statute and by custom, as was also the case in Byzantium with respect to the billon and copper coinage. Another solution was the substitution of a new piece of greater intrinsic as well as nominal value as the basis of the system of account: quattrino for piccolo (Florence), soldino for piccolo (Venice), blanca for dinero (Castile), schilling for witten for pfennig (Lubeck).10 The original link moneys, if they continued to be minted, usually ended up as token currencies of pure copper or close to it and almost too small to handle.

The “problem of the standard” does not seem to have been posed in the same terms in the Byzantine Empire, at least as long as the state enjoyed a monopoly of minting, also because electrum coinage (debased simply by raising its silver content) was preferred to an inherently unstable “bimetallic” system as in the West. In fact, what chiefly distinguished the monetary experience of the Byzantine Empire during most of its long history was the state’s surprisingly effective control over mint output and the

9Day, “The Problem of the Standard.”

10Day, “Les monnaies de compte me´die´vales.”

Monetary Mechanisms, East and West

971

money supply and, to a lesser degree perhaps, over prices and the trade in precious metals. As late as the fourteenth century, monetary policy was shaped more in the interests of the imperial finances than in the interests of trade, which doubtless helps to explain the penury of merchant capital and the absence of the sort of financial institutions that developed among Byzantium’s western trading partners.

Minting activity and monetary circulation in the eastern Mediterranean in the twelfth to fifteenth centuries depended in large measure on precious metals originating in the West.11 This unilateral movement of metallic stocks was due essentially, as noted elsewhere, to a permanent deficit in the European balance of trade. It was the specie and bullion introduced by western merchants and Crusaders that permitted the return to silver coinage in the East after two centuries of a monetary circulation based on copper and gold. As time passed, the better-known European currencies, the Venetian grosso and ducat, the Florentine florin, the Neapolitan carlino, mingled with and on occasion supplanted the Muslim and Byzantine coinages. “There came a day in the fourteenth century,” wrote Marc Bloch, “when hyperperes were valued in ducats.”12 It is not surprising, therefore, that at the end of the fourteenth century the decline in European stocks had severe repercussions in the East. According to a contemporary, the year 1398 marked the start of a veritable silver famine in Egypt, where “the minting of dirhams was very infrequent so much silver had been wasted in the manufacture of saddles, silverware, etc. and also because it had ceased to arrive from the country of the Franks.”13 The crisis in minting assured the triumph of the Venetian ducat. The Egyptian chronicler al-Makrizi reported at that time that “the circulation of the ducat had spread to the principal cities of the (Muslim) world to the point of becoming the common currency of trade.”14 And a Venetian text a few years later confirmed that Syrian merchants insisted on being paid in ducats rather than silver. But it was silver that normally enjoyed a premium in the eastern Mediterranean (even resulting for a time, in the 14th century, in a speculative “exchange of metals” between Venice and Constantinople). This phenomenon seems to have been due, in the first instance, to the insatiable demand for silver emanating from the Indian subcontinent, which also helps to account for the chronic shortage of silver currency on the eastern markets. Emmanuel Piloti evokes in this connection a sort of monetary frontier limited to the ducat: “The merchants of Venice procure their spices at Damascus and Alexandria because their gold money is not current in India or the Spice Islands.”15 In other words, most of the 300,000 or so gold ducats shipped from Venice to the Levant in normal years in the fifteenth century remained in that region. It would seem, therefore, that the essential reason for the success of the ducat on the markets of the eastern Mediterranean in the late Middle Ages was the deterioration, followed sometimes by

11See J. Day, “Colonialisme mone´taire en Me´diterrane´e au Moyen Age,” in Monnaies et marche´s au Moyen Age (as above, note 3), 145–47, for references.

12M. Bloch, “Le proble`me de l’or au Moyen Age,” in Bloch, Me´langes historiques (Paris, 1963), 2:860.

13Day, “Colonialisme mone´taire,” 145–47.

14Day, “Colonialisme mone´taire,” 145–47.

15Day, “Colonialisme mone´taire,” 145–47.

972 JOHN DAY

the disappearance, of the local silver currencies, which was caused by the accelerated drain of that metal to India and the Far East. This movement combined with the wastage of metallic stocks in war and their immobilization in gold and silver artifacts to exacerbate the effects in the Levant of the crisis in mining and minting in Europe.

Given the monetary dependence of the Near East on the European mining industry in the twelfth to fifteenth centuries, it is not surprising that the two regions shared a common economic destiny, at least if one subscribes to Fernand Braudel’s view that monetary movements are the “transmission belt” of the economic conjuncture. Population, land settlement, commerce, manufacturing, and the monetization of the economy were making rapid strides in the East as well as in the West by the time of the First Crusade, and the movement seems to have shifted into high gear in both regions in the twelfth to thirteenth centuries. In the crisis years of the fourteenth to fifteenth centuries, on the other hand, the Levant’s monetary dependence on Europe operated in a negative sense and was naturally overshadowed by the Turkish conquests.

The Role of the Byzantine State in the Economy

Nicolas Oikonomides

The adherence of Byzantium to tradition was a feature of every aspect of state life, profoundly affecting relations between the state and the economy and determining the extent to which the former intervened in the latter. However, although the state’s theoretical principles were, of course, founded on tradition, when the time came to put them into practice a realistic approach prevailed: theory survived and continued to have its effect, though without substantially altering the true situation. Those in power intervened frequently in economic life and at many points of it, working on the basis of the old theory that the purpose of action of any kind was to foster the smooth operation of the state machine, of the empire “by the grace of God.” In reality, however, the changes that came about were profound, and they came about without disturbing the theoretical surface of the omnipotence of the state, and of the emperor in particular.

It has been said that Byzantium had a “directed” economy, since the intervention of the state was manifest even in relation to activities, such as trade, that would normally be beyond such controls. This description has now been abandoned, and the economy of Byzantium is now seen as “restrained” by the state; in other words, it was an economy that functioned on the basis of the freedom of transactions but in which the state intervened to prevent the excessive accumulation of wealth, the suppression of the weakest, and the exploitation of the citizens/consumers. Where this intervention is concerned, the Byzantine state was substantively different from the medieval states of western Europe, which functioned under a system of effective decentralization.

One of the unchanging characteristics of the Byzantine administration was its centralization: everything passed through the center, everything was controlled from the center. Here there was a fundamental contradiction between theory and reality, since in actuality phenomena of decentralization are often to be observed. However, the contradiction was blunted by the adaptability of the Byzantine state, which was able, when necessary, to confine its control to the bare essentials. In the last centuries of Byzantium, a degree of decentralization is evident, but even then the state kept control

This chapter was translated by John Solman.

974 NICOLAS OIKONOMIDES

of many parts of the decentralized economy, determining the tax obligations of even those peasants who lived on land from which it collected nothing.1

Sources

The fact that the Byzantines were so attached to tradition causes problems when one is assessing the reliability of the source material, especially since very few archives have survived, and consequently it would be futile to hope to assemble a long series of information of an economic nature. No more than a few thousand Byzantine documents of the seventh to the fifteenth century have survived to the present day, and of course they cover the entire spectrum of life. Furthermore, the majority of these documents come from monastic archives in specific areas (such as Mount Athos, Patmos, western Asia Minor, Chios, Pontos, and Thessaly), and the information they contain concerns economic activities of a specific kind, principally the cultivation, on the sharecropping system, of land that was (or might become) privileged since it belonged to monasteries. Needless to say, the existence or otherwise of privileges is of decisive importance in determining the role of the state in the agricultural economy.

It is true, of course, that the monastic archives also contain documents concerning private property, usually land belonging to lay people that subsequently came into the possession of the monastery by purchase, by donation, or by the owner becoming a monk in the foundation. There are not many of these documents, however, and the laymen to whom they refer were often privileged.

Where the role of the state in other forms of economic life—trade, manufacturing, the exploitation of raw materials—is concerned, there is in effect no archival material at all. The comparatively few documents that have survived are mostly in Italian archives and deal only in passing with the Byzantine state.

It follows that the primary sources upon which we might have expected to be able to draw for information about the role of the state in the economic life of the country are very scanty, almost nonexistent. Technical texts that preserve details and information of incontrovertible accuracy about the public economy—such as the detailed lists of expenditure on the campaigns against Crete in 911 and 949, discussed later (p. 1015)—are rare. Most of our information comes from sources of a narrative or regulatory nature.

The narrative sources sometimes relate what was said about this or that measure that the emperor had taken, frequently distorting it in accordance with the author’s sympathies. Although this information often reflects the reaction of public opinion (or a part of it) to fiscal policy, it is littered with traps because it also expresses a given political position. We have descriptions of the measures taken by the Isaurian emperors written by monks who were sworn enemies of those rulers for reasons that were not primarily economic, but were bound up with the fundamentally theological and

1 In the text that follows, and especially in discussing the agricultural economy and taxation to the time of the Komnenian reforms, I have made extensive use of N. Oikonomides, Fiscalite´ et exemption fiscale `a Byzance, IXe–XIe s. (Athens, 1996).